Contents
Labour supply
The income elasticity
The substitution elasticity
An illustrative example
Capital gains elasticity
How PolicyEngine models behavioural responses
Comparing static and dynamic analysis
Conclusion
Public policies change incentives and behaviours. When governments introduce or modify policies, individuals respond by adjusting their decisions. Workers may change their work hours,
This report presents how PolicyEngine currently models three key behavioural responses to policy changes :
To model these responses, we apply elasticities, which quantify the magnitude of the response: larger elasticities indicate stronger behavioural responses, while smaller ones suggest more limited adjustments. PolicyEngine empowers users to set their own elasticities, while we apply our best guesses in our reports. This review describes these responses and our selected elasticities.
PolicyEngine models how individuals adjust their earnings through income and substitution effects. For example, one might work less if they have more income (they purchase leisure with income effects), or if they take home less for an additional hour of work (they substitute leisure over consumption at the margin).
When people become richer, they might choose to work less. The income elasticity measures this behaviour - how much work changes when net income changes after taxes and transfers.
By default, PolicyEngine applies the
People work partly based on how much they keep from each extra hour of work. The substitution elasticity measures how work changes when this reward changes. For example, higher tax rates or steeper benefit phase-outs mean keeping less from each additional hour, which might lead to less overtime or part-time work. By default, PolicyEngine applies the
Unlike the
To understand how these elasticities work, consider a worker earning £30,000 per year. This worker currently faces a marginal tax rate of
For this worker earning £14.42 per hour (£30,000/2,080 hours), the take-home pay per extra hour drops from £10.38 to £10.21 under the new policy – a 1.6% decrease. Using PolicyEngine's central estimates, we calculate two effects:
The net effect combines these responses: 0.4% decrease minus 0.035% increase equals a 0.365% decrease. Given the baseline of £30,000 earnings and 2,080 hours, this translates to a predicted 7 fewer work hours and £109 less earnings per year.
When tax rates on investment gains change, people adjust when they sell their investments,
We have not identified any UK-specific studies on capital gains elasticities, so PolicyEngine relies on US research evidence. US studies distinguish between permanent elasticities (long-term responses to sustained tax changes) and transitory elasticities (temporary responses as people time their sales around tax changes). Dowd and McClelland (2019)
PolicyEngine uses an elasticity of -0.7 as a default amount for the UK context, reflecting our belief that UK capital gains respond less to policy change than US capital gains do. Several factors drive this difference: the US has more tax-advantaged investment vehicles, more generous real estate tax treatment,
By default, the PolicyEngine web app assumes no behavioural responses. When users specify nonzero elasticities, it adds behavioural responses to its tax-benefit calculations. For each simulated reform, the model first computes the effects of policy changes on income and tax rates. Then, it estimates three behavioural changes: how total income changes affect work, how marginal tax changes affect work hours, and how tax rates influence investment timing. Because each person’s earnings can affect household net income differently, we calculate marginal tax rates with respect to each of the top three earners, and apply each of their labour supply responses, separately. Finally, we recalculate taxes and benefits following the earnings and capital gains change.
Here we demonstrate how incorporating behavioural responses affects policy analysis by examining a tax reform proposed by the UK government in October 2024: change to Capital Gains Tax. For a detailed analysis of this and other reforms proposed in the Autumn Budget, see
In estimating the impacts of this reform, we model how individuals with capital gains respond to changes in their marginal tax rate. The table below compares the five-year revenue impacts under both static and dynamic scenarios.
In this report, we present how PolicyEngine models three behavioural responses:
While this report focuses on these three core elasticities, PolicyEngine is expanding its behavioural modelling capabilities. For instance, we developed responses to
Chetty, R., Guren, A., Manoli, D., & Weber, A. (2011). Are Micro and Macro Labor Supply Elasticities Consistent? A Review of Evidence on the Intensive and Extensive Margins. American Economic Review, 101(3), 471–475.
Saez, E., Slemrod, J., & Giertz, S. H. (2012). The Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates: A Critical Review. Journal of Economic Literature, 50(1), 3-50.
Feldstein, M., Behavioural Responses to Taxation: Lessons from the Tax Reform Act of 1986, American Economic Review, 1995.
Burman, Leonard E., and William C. Randolph. "Measuring permanent responses to capital-gains tax changes in panel data." The American Economic Review (1994): 794-809.
Dowd, Tim, and Robert McClelland. 2019. "The Bunching of Capital Gains Realizations." National Tax Journal 72(2): 323-358.
Auten, Gerald, and Charles Clotfelter. 1982. "Permanent versus Transitory Tax Effects and the Realization of Capital Gains." Quarterly Journal of Economics 97(4): 613-632.
U.S. Congress, House Committee on Financial Services, The Future of Housing in America: A Comparison of the United Kingdom and United States Models of Affordable Housing, hearing, 114th Congress, 2nd session, May 12, 2016.
Odean, T. (1999). Do investors trade too much? American Economic Review, 89(5), 1279-1298.
Financial Expert. (n.d.).
vahid ahmadi
Research Associate at PolicyEngine
Get the latests posts delivered right to your inbox.
PolicyEngine is a registered charity with the Charity Commission of England and Wales (no. 1210532) and as a private company limited by guarantee with Companies House (no. 15023806).
© 2025 PolicyEngine. All rights reserved.